THE CONQUEST OF BREAD
by P. Kropotkin
CHAPTER XV
The Division of Labour
I
POLITICAL ECONOMY has always confined itself to
stating facts occurring in society, and justifying
them in the interest of the dominant class. Thus
it is in favour of the division of labour created by
industry. Having found it profitable to capitalists
it has set it up as a principle.
Look at the village smith, said Adam Smith,
the father of modern Political Economy. If he has
never been accustomed to making nails he will
only succeed by hard toil in forging two to three
hundred a day, and even then they will be bad.
But if this same smith has never done anything
but nails, he will easily supply as many as two
thousand three hundred in the course of a day.
And Smith hastened to the conclusion--"Divide
labour, specialize, go on specializing; let us have
smiths who only know how to make heads or points
of nails, and by this means we shall produce more.
We shall grow rich."
That a smith sentenced for life to the making
of heads of nails would lose all interest in his work,
would be entirely at the mercy of his employer
with his limited handicraft, would be out of work
four months out of twelve, and that his wages would
decrease when he could be easily replaced by an
apprentice, Smith did not think of it when he
exclaimed--"Long live the division of labour.
This is the real gold-mine that will enrich the
nation!" And all joined in the cry.
And later on, when a Sismondi or a J. B. Say
began to understand that the division of labour,
instead of enriching the whole nation, only enriches
the rich, and that the worker, who for life is doomed
to making the eighteenth part of a pin, grows
stupid and sinks into poverty--what did official
economists propose? Nothing! They did not say
to themselves that by a lifelong grind at one and
the same mechanical toil the worker would lose
his intelligence and his spirit of invention, and
that, on the contrary, a variety of occupations
would result in considerably augmenting the
productivity of a nation. But this is the very
issue now before us.
If, however, only economists preached the
permanent and often hereditary division of labour,
we might allow them to preach it as much as they
pleased. But ideas taught by doctors of science
filter into men's minds and pervert them; and
from repeatedly hearing the division of labour,
profits, interest, credit, etc., spoken of as problems
long since solved, men, and workers too, end by
arguing like economists, and by venerating the
same fetishes.
Thus we see a number of socialists, even those
who have not feared to point out the mistakes of
science, justifying the division of labour. Talk
to them about the organization of work during
the Revolution, and they answer that the division
of labour must be maintained; that if you
sharpened pins before the Revolution you must go
on sharpening them after. True, you will not have
to work more than five hours a day, but you will
have to sharpen pins all your life, while others will
make designs for machines that will enable you to
sharpen hundreds of millions of pins during your
lifetime; and others again will be specialists in the
higher branches of literature, science, and art, etc.
You were born to sharpen pins while Pasteur was
born to invent the inoculation against anthrax,
and the Revolution will leave you both to your
respective employments. Well, it is this horrible
principle, so noxious to society, so brutalizing to
the individual, source of so much harm, that we
propose to discuss in its divers manifestations.
We know the consequences of the division of
labour full well. It is evident that we are divided
into two classes: on the one hand, producers
who consume very little and are exempt from
thinking because they only do physical work,
and who work badly because their brains remain
inactive; and on the other hand, the consumers,
who, producing little or hardly anything, have the
privilege of thinking for the others, and who
think badly because the whole world of those who
toil with their hands is unknown to them. The
labourers of the soil know nothing of machinery
those who work at machinery ignore everything
about agriculture. The ideal of modern industry
is a child tending a machine that he cannot and
must not understand, and a foreman who fines him
if his attention flags for a moment. The ideal
of industrial agriculture is to do away with the
agricultural labourer altogether and to set a man
who does odd jobs to tend a steam-plough or a
threshing-machine. The division of labour means
labelling and stamping men for life--some to
splice ropes in factories, some to be foremen in a
business, others to shove huge coal-baskets in a
particular part of a mine; but none of them to have
any idea of machinery as a whole, nor of business,
nor of mines. And thereby they destroy the love
of work and the capacity for invention that, at the
beginning of modern industry, created the machinery
on which we pride ourselves so much.
What they have done for individuals, they also
wanted to do for nations. Humanity was to be
divided into national workshops, having each its
speciality. Russia, we were taught, was destined
by nature to grow corn; England to spin cotton;
Belgium to weave cloth; while Switzerland was
to train nurses and governesses. Moreover, each
separate city was to establish a speciality. Lyons
was to weave silk, Auvergne to make lace, and
Paris fancy articles. Economists believed that
specialization opened an immense field for production
and consumption, and that an era of limitless wealth for
mankind was at hand.
But these great hopes vanished as fast as technical
knowledge spread abroad. As long as England stood
alone as a weaver of cotton, and as a metal-worker
on a large scale; as long as only Paris made artistic
fancy articles, etc., all went well, economists
could preach so-called division of labour without
being refuted.
But a new current of thought induced all civilized
nations to manufacture for themselves. They
found it advantageous to produce what they
formerly received from other countries, or from their
colonies, which in their turn aimed at emancipating
themselves from the mother-country. Scientific
discoveries universalized the methods of production
and henceforth it was useless to pay an exorbitant
price abroad for what could easily be produced at
home. Does not then this industrial revolution
strike a crushing blow at the theory of the division
of labour which was supposed to be so sound?
This text was taken from a 1st edition of The Conquest of Bread,
G. P. Putnam's Sons, New York and London, 1906.
Go to Chapter 16.
Return to Table of Contents.
Return to Anarchy Archives.
|